1 Introduction
The platform economy has now entered its second decade, and researchers have investigated a wide range of platform outcomes, including inequality, trust, and racial discrimination (for a review see Schor & Vallas, 2021). There are also many studies of workers’ experiences, particularly on lower-paid apps such as ride-hail, shopping, and delivery (Ravenelle, 2019; Griesbach et al., 2019; Robinson, 2017; Cameron, 2018; Ladegaard et al., 2018). These accounts have tended to describe a common platform experience, typically that of highly committed workers. Schor et al. (2020a) have argued that the literature has not sufficiently addressed how unique features of the platform model — low barriers to entry, choice of hours, and the ease of working for multiple platforms at once — produce a heterogeneous labor force. Here, we explore another dimension of a heterogeneous platform workforce, namely the diversity of economic orientations of earners, or to use a term from economics, their “behavioral models.” To sociologists, the presence of multiple behavioral models, especially among professionals or the self-employed, is not a novel finding (Fridman, 2020). Users of these platforms, who tend to be young and highly educated (PEW Research Center, 2016a; 2016b; Schor & Cansoy, 2019), profess a range of motivations for participating (Fitzmaurice et al., 2020; Ravenelle, 2017) and their dependence on platform income also varies (Schor et al., 2020a). Therefore, the existence of multiple behavioral models in this sector may be unsurprising. However, as Beckert (1996; 2003) notes, sociologists have failed to theorize “models of economic action,” i.e., how individuals translate a series of preferences into behavior.
Using in-depth interview data from 102 respondents on three platforms (Airbnb, TaskRabbit, and StocksyUnited) we find that within individual platforms, there are diverse strategies for governing earning behaviors. Iterating between models found in the literature and our data, we have identified three main orientations. Some are maximizers, engaged in the kinds of activities ascribed to homo economicus, economists’ archetypal rational actor. A second group displays a more social orientation, and although these earners are also interested in money, they are not optimizers on the financial margin. They have other goals, including sociability. But they also draw ethical boundaries around their platform work, reject opportunities that don’t reflect their social preferences, or act to gain recognition. We call this type homo socialis. A third group, which we term homo instrumentalis, displays neither maximizing behaviors nor strong social preferences. They merely aim to earn, and do so in casual, habitual, or targeted ways.
We provide an account of the three models and discuss platforms’ tolerance for the heterogeneity we find by discussing how earner diversity aligns with the companies’ imperatives for growth. This allows us to contribute to theorizing questions such as whether platforms represent something different from conventional businesses and the extent to which they are novel forms. The paper proceeds with a discussion of theories of the platform firm, a brief discussion of the three types of earners we discovered, our methods, findings, and a section on platform responses.
2 Theorizing the Platform Firm
The presence of diverse models of economic behavior within a single platform’s labor force raises questions about the nature of this type of firm. Is it more like a market, in which diversity among participants is tolerated, especially if they are willing to take lower returns? Or are these platforms more like bureaucratic firms that attempt to control the behavior of their employees? Scholars have begun to develop understandings of platform firms which shed light on these questions. Vallas and Schor (2020) identified four approaches to theorizing digital platforms — efficiency accounts, “Uberization” and precarity narratives, algorithmic control, and a fourth hybrid conceptualization. A second set of issues concerns the behavior of earners. Is there anything novel about how people use and earn in this context, or are conventional models of economic behavior sufficient? The literature is less explicit on this question, so our discussion addresses implicit assumptions.
Efficiency accounts, which come mainly from economists, focus on the ability of digital technology to reduce transactions costs and increase efficiency (Horton & Zeckhauser, 2016; Sundararajan, 2016). This results in a shift from the firm (a command and control entity) toward the market (a voluntaristic, atomistic structure), as well as toward smaller, peer-to-peer entities (Einav et al., 2016). This view is consistent with an earlier shift to seeing firms as a “nexus-of-contracts” (Jensen & Meckling, 1976) which Davis (2016a) argues helped create “Nikefication”, i.e., the outsourcing of functions, and the “vanishing” of the American corporation (Davis, 2016b). On the question of behavioral models, the economics literature has been silent, assuming that the standard models — either the rational actor or its behavioral economics cousin — prevail.
Outside of economics, the dominant perspective is “Uberization.” In this view, the platform is little more than a “web page” (Davis, 2016a, p 513). Grabher and van Tuijl (2020) formulate this shift as going from employment to a “gig.” Uberization is the culmination of trends such as fissuring (Weil, 2014) and precarious work (Kalleberg, (2013), which describe the breakdown of stable employment and benefits, the shift of costs onto workers, and the increasing insecurity of labor. As with the economic approach, the precarity literature generally does not focus on the heterogeneity of the labor force other than considering variations in levels of precarity. While some accounts do note that earners fall into different categories (Ravenelle, 2019), the focus is on the common worker experience of bearing costs and risks (For an exception, see Manriquez, 2019). Similarly, while ethnographic accounts describe differences among people, this approach generally avoids theorizing behavioral models and has not provided a distinctive analysis of economic action on platforms.
The third approach sees platform firms as novel entities on account of their ability to control labor via algorithms (Aneesh, 2009; Rosenblat & Stark, 2016; Griesbach et al., 2019). Algorithmic control is enhanced by information asymmetries that enhance the power of the platforms over workers. While this view does not deny the precarity of workers, it emphasizes top-down authority, an all-powerful Panopticon collecting user data (van Doorn & Badger, 2020) and a break from previous methods of control. The algorithmic approach does not typically address issues of socio-economic, demographic, or behavioral heterogeneity among the workforce, at least not from the perspective of what it might mean for understanding these firms. Instead, the key variable is the power that technology affords to platform management. A related view focuses less on labor control but on the ways in which technology affords platforms even more power than conventional firms, and allows them to expand their command and control to the markets they operate in (Kenney & Zysman, 2019; Srnicek, 2016). This literature harkens back to the early postwar era with its focus on dominant firms with monopoly power.
The fourth view sees the platform firm as novel because it is a hybrid form, combining organizational and technological factors to create a new entity. It emphasizes the networked and market relations of firms, and their departure from the conventional hierarchical corporation. Yet these accounts also hold that firms retain power over the parties with which they transact, including labor. Two contributions are especially relevant. Watkins and Stark (2018), who studied platforms in a variety of sectors, argue that these entities have evolved into a “Mobius” firm. They have gone beyond the simple network formulation and are able to co-opt resources that are both internal and external to the firm. A related argument by Kornberger et al. (2017) is that platforms are unique because they employ novel accounting methods that move from traditional hierarchical categories to heterarchies. By introducing new evaluative methods such as ratings and reputational systems, platform firms can radically decentralize control and simultaneously centralize power. This hybrid formulation — decentralization with concentrated power — is common to this genre of platform theorization.
We (Schor et al., 2020b) have made a similar argument about the platform economy, arguing that these firms have enacted a “retreat from control” as they allow earners to choose hours and schedules and organize their labor processes relatively autonomously. While autonomy varies across platforms, in comparison to conventional service labor, platform work is generally less scripted or directed by the employer (Leidner, 1993). But while the platform allows the worker the freedom to “be their own boss,” it retains power and certain forms of control, including through the use of market discipline. Market discipline may be especially relevant in low-wage sectors, such as ride-hail and delivery, where requisite skills are generally available throughout the population, which gives firms considerable latitude to recruit new earners, a key lever for affecting supply. Finally, we note that “permissiveness” varies by platform, and lower-wage workers are subject to more control than those with more market power.
Willingness to allow worker freedom of choice over schedules and total hours is a unique feature of platform management. It produces a consequential aspect of platform work — heterogeneity in when and how much earners choose to work on the platform.1 There has been relatively little attention to how workforce heterogeneity might manifest in other ways. In our research, we discovered that within and across platforms, earners exhibit different modes of earning. This finding adds another distinctive aspect to platform firms, which we explore below.
3 Models of Economic Behavior
How should we understand economic behavior? While economists have historically produced varied answers to this question, by the 1970s, they had coalesced around a single idea for representing and modeling economic behavior — the rational maximizer. However, nearly as soon as they had, “behavioral economists” came along to trouble that fiction, with a wealth of empirical findings that violated the principles of selfishness (“fairness norms”), revealed time inconsistency in preferences, loss aversion, and non-linear probability weighting of alternatives (Kahneman, 2011). These developments revitalized ideas such as income targeting and Simon’s (1957) bounded rationality and satisficing. Among economic sociologists, whose project began as a critique of the neo-classical model, the focus has been on how structures inhibit maximizing behavior. Approaches include Bourdieu’s (1984) habitus, social networks (Granovetter, 1973), Polanyian embeddedness (Block & Somers, 2014), and “relational” economic sociology (Zelizer, 2013). However, given the diverse ways economic sociologists have explained economic outcomes, they have generally not focused explicitly on models of economic behavior. Indeed, Frank Dobbin (2007) has made the point that economic sociologists have generally accepted the view that agents seek profits. Jens Beckert (2003; 1996) has argued that economic sociologists have generally not constructed their own “models of economic action.”
And what of platform actors? Which of these conceptualizations do they conform to? We found three distinct orientations — economicus, socialis, and instrumentalis. Before discussing each, however, we want to stress that all of our respondents are active on the platforms in order to earn money. If they were not, they would be more likely to be participating on gift exchange sites such as Couchsurfing (a free alternative to Airbnb) or time banks (multi-lateral barter service exchanges). Therefore, our analysis does not replicate well-worn tropes of altruism versus self-interest or money versus love (Folbre, 2001). What we find is that among a financially-motivated group, there are major differences in how people think, act and transact. That said, we note that we have not included low-wage platforms, where we would expect more conformity among earners. However, our ongoing interviews with workers in ride-hail, food delivery and shopping also suggest some diversity of orientation.
The first group we call homo economicus. These are classic rational, self-interested actors who pursue optimal outcomes. While they focus on maximizing earnings, what’s distinctive is how they do it. They develop individualized strategies to maximize the prices they can command, often by seeking out market information. They pursue actionable information about costs, earnings, and how to improve their margins. They are engaged in continuous calculations, keep spreadsheets, pay careful attention to costs, and sometimes experiment with pricing. They strategize about ways to increase their earnings, by improving or expanding their real estate assets, sub-contracting tasks or services, or investing in their platform activities, which they think of in largely commercial terms. Ultimately, they understand themselves, and others, through a lens of idealized rational action.
Noting the shortcomings of the homo economicus model, the “new economic sociology” of the early 1980s questioned how social networks might clarify seemingly illogical behaviors not otherwise explained by the rational actor model (Granovetter, 1973). At economic sociology’s core is the claim that economic activity has a social dimension that is integral to understanding why actors make fiscal decisions. Building on this insight, Zelizer argued that economic relations were not merely embedded in social context but that they were “continuously negotiated” and “meaningfully interpersonal” (Zelizer, 2012, p. 146). Zelizer defined this as a relational package in which actors balance four unique elements: distinctive social ties, a set of economic transactions, media, and negotiated meanings. This framing suggests a robust social actor who will weigh social incentives in their economic decisions. We term this category homo socialis.
Homines sociales have varied motivations and behaviors, such as meeting people and socializing, building community, or avoiding status threats. They are unified by strategies that are guided, first and foremost, by relational incentives and social considerations. They value income, but instead of spending energy tinkering with the bottom line, homines sociales turn their attention towards maintaining personal ethics, seeking validation, and fostering social connections. While a good number of homines sociales are prosocial, this category also includes individuals who draw strong boundaries to avoid particular interactions, such as tasks which involve status insults or hassles they would rather avoid. Some engage in discriminatory behaviors, even at the expense of making money. In short, homines sociales do not prioritize income maximization. Nor are they particularly oriented to calculative completeness or searching for market information. They are happy to participate in economic transactions that can coexist with their social specifications, but abstain from economic opportunities that violate their larger “social” orientations.
The third type we have identified, the homo instrumentalis, is less discussed in the literature, either in economics or sociology. Like homo economicus, this type is strongly oriented to making money, rather than to social relationships or social goals. However, their relationship with money is largely instrumental. Some earn for a specific purpose, such as for rent, debt payments, vacations, or even beer. Others operate with a target income — when it is reached, they reduce economic activity.2 Our homo instrumentalis lacks a coherent strategy, uses simple heuristics and resists pressures to do more, or to optimize participation. They often settle for the “good enough” outcomes described by Simon (1957). They are satisficing agents, who are not compelled to spend further effort searching for marginally better outcomes (Caplin et al., 2011).
4 Methods
Our goal is to explain a variety of participant orientations in the platform economy. We therefore focused on platforms with different business models, barriers to entry, and remuneration structures. We discuss three platforms — Airbnb, TaskRabbit, and StocksyUnited. Airbnb is a platform where hosts rent rooms or entire homes on a short-term basis, at prices that are significantly higher per night than long-term rentals. Hosts set the price, manage booking requests, and clean and prepare the home for stays. Depending on the characteristics of the home, hosts might spend time with their guests, for instance if they share a kitchen or a living room. TaskRabbit is a platform for a wide range of tasks, but most are either delivery, cleaning or manual labor tasks such as moving (Cullen & Farronato, 2018). In the first version of the platform, workers used an auction model to bid on posted tasks. In 2014, auctions were replaced with a model where customers search an inventory of Taskers and select one based on hourly prices and profile descriptions. The third platform, StocksyUnited, is an artist-owned and governed stock photography co-operative. It has a competitive, limited membership of over 1000, and members make major decisions. Members’ work is included on the company’s website and sold at a flat rate determined by the management. In contrast to Airbnb and TaskRabbit providers, Stocksy artists do not set prices. However, they can boost their sales and increase earnings by investing in photo shoots and tailoring their work to the market. They also control how many photographs they submit.
We conducted 102 semi-structured interviews, scheduled for 60 minutes, although some lasted longer. Most Airbnb and TaskRabbit respondents were located in Greater Boston and were interviewed in person, but a few lived in other US cities and were interviewed by videoconference. Stocksy interviews were done online, as members span the globe. Airbnb and TaskRabbit interviews began in 2013, and continued until 2017; Stocksy interviews were conducted in 2017 and 2018. We recruited Airbnb earners initially by messaging them on the platform, but switched to snowball sampling and social media as the platform deactivated the accounts we were using. For TaskRabbit, we hired interviewees through the platform with the interview as the “task.” We recruited Stocksy members with the help of management, who provided a list of names and emails. We contacted members and asked them to schedule an interview.3 Compensation was initially $30 per interview, and was subsequently increased to $40. Demographic details of our sample can be found in the appendix.
All interviews were transcribed. For the qualitative analysis, we sorted our interview transcripts by platform category and assigned a principal coder to each group, to make it easier to compare different logics within the respective platforms. We began with a round of open coding, in which we developed basic descriptive categories around narratives of self, platform goals, and economic practices, which we discussed as a team in subsequent memos and meetings. For example, we noted that some Airbnb hosts used demand-estimation strategies in order to optimize their prices. Quotes from such participants were distributed to all team members and in discussions we agreed that such a practice is characteristic of homo economicus, because it contributes to the larger goal of maximizing platform earnings. After agreeing on ideal-types for economicus, socialis, and instrumentalis, which we detailed in a shared codebook, we read all transcripts and coded all participants in a round of systematic and theoretical coding. Throughout the process, we frequently returned to the codebook, made adjustments when necessary, and continued to write and talk about our participants and their practices, until we had formed full coding consensus on our participants (Table 1). We had a small number of hybrid cases which displayed features of more than one model. This process meant that while we began with three ideal models from the literature, we developed and elaborated on their features through analysis of our data.
5 Findings
Homo Economicus
Homines economici are not distinguished from others by their motives. As noted above, nearly everyone in the sample is interested in making money. Rather, they are characterized by their maximizing orientation to earning and efficiency. In the words of Ryan, a Tasker, being on the platform is “very much a cost/benefit analysis that I run at every opportunity.” For many, these calculations result in effective strategies to set their prices or investing time and resources into the work to maximize their earnings. They also fastidiously document and calculate expenses and earnings, and display great personal command of the financial details of their participation. Their orientation is often reflected in their discourse, which analogizes various aspects of the platform and their own participation to an idealized market.
For some, maximizing orientations developed over time. Gustav is a full-time photographer who had moved from Sweden to Mexico, which allowed his Stocksy income to stretch further. Gustav readily reinvests his money in Stocksy, hiring local experts that get him access to unique spaces such as medical facilities. Gustav explains:
Follow the money is a way to do it. You could keep it a hobby but I figured out very quickly that certain photos don’t sell at all or very little… So yeah, if I want to have this as my job, if I want to have some income, I better focus on the thing that sells.
On Airbnb, thirty-one-year-old Pete, born and raised in Boston by parents who immigrated from Cape Verde, had a similar experience. In 2011, he purchased a big house from a 90-year-old who had lived there for decades and he now sublets several rooms to pay for renovation costs and the mortgage. Initially he was “afraid” of using Airbnb, but an encounter with an Uber driver who had two successful Airbnb listings convinced him to give it a try.
I started off at $60 a night because … I used to rent [out the room] for $600 a month … So even if I rent it for ten nights I’ll still be making what I used to make. And it got booked up. … So in June I’m like, why don’t I charge more? So I started charging more, and I was getting it. … My most successful month was August where I made $5,500 dollars.
The maximization orientation leads participants to identify platform-specific strategies to reach their goals. On Airbnb and TaskRabbit, price setting is an important strategy. Stanley, who is white and 26, manages his short-term rental unit on a full-time basis and says he can reach 90% occupancy during busy periods. He adjusts his prices during the year, especially during winter, when demand is low, but also during the week, “because not every night is worth the same.” He uses Airbnb’s price suggestions, which adjust rates by seasonality, but overrules the suggestions at times to further optimize his earnings.
The algorithm that they use to determine [prices]… doesn’t really scale that well to each individual city because there might be an event coming to town or something. Their price tips aren’t going to be all that great for predicting that. So, you do kind of have to know. It is a little bit of a learning curve…I’ve kind of done that to adjust the price.
Rich, a white Tasker in his 40s, struggles with poverty on TaskRabbit and is just able to pay his monthly bills. It is not for lack of trying. He has unique strategies for securing earnings:
What I often do in order to get something assigned to me is the guy may say, ‘I'm thinking $100,’ and I'll be, like, ‘Look, unless it's a total train wreck when I get there, I'll do it for $75.’ So I always just, like, bring the price way down. And then at the end they end up just paying you the money anyway.
Rich is also aggressive in his pursuit of tasks: “To me it's a numbers game. Maybe I have 40 open bids going at once. Maybe that's not very smart. But if it's a numbers game, why not?” Rich’s “game” analogy is telling; by pursuing multiple bids at once, technically allowed but discouraged by the platform, he is able to pick and choose the most lucrative opportunities.
Ralph, 26, moved to the US from Haiti for his college education. While finishing his degree, working a full-time job and pursuing many opportunities to make money on the side he had completed about 15 jobs on TaskRabbit, sufficient for him to develop a keen understanding of the prices he could command:
Personally, everything over $50 [an hour] is great…You get a lot of $55s or $62s. Those are great to me. Because over $50, if you spend two hours, that's $100 right there. Even though …you end up getting paid like $42 [because of the platform’s fee], which is still like closer to $100 if you spend two hours. So, me, I always, if it's over $50, I'm always down for it. I take a lot of, like, $40 an hour, $45s and stuff. Those are good, too. I don't bother taking the $25 because you get paid like $19, $18 or even $16. It's not worth it.
On Stocksy, the cooperative sets a flat licensing fee for all photos, so members are left to pursue strategies to maximize their sales volume. Some photographers seek editorial critique to improve their work, while others study sales data to boost their sales. Milo, who is white and 43, used to work in software development but had transitioned into making his photography hobby his primary work. His strategy to maximize sales volume is “[d]ata driven…”
If I want to grow the Stocksy portfolio I would have a look at search terms. So I would analyze what are people searching, in which different areas in the world? What are they looking for?"
Homines economici on Airbnb and TaskRabbit pay close attention to prices, time spent, and competition. Aaron, a white 25-year-old pharma researcher with a condo in the heart of Boston uses Airbnb to finance his wedding. He spends considerable time figuring out how to price his unit:
You do a little comparative analysis to see what the hotel rooms are in the area … and what other people’s homes look like that are at the price range you’re at, what people are willing to pay for homes that are, in my opinion, a little less extravagantly nice than my home, and be, like, “Oh, if people are paying for this home at that rate I can go up a little higher, too.”
Aaron’s attention to what the market will bear is typical of a number of the people in this group. Eric, who is white and 31, manages a friend’s apartment on Airbnb. He tries to maximize revenue and minimize his workload, mainly by avoiding short stays because of the work of communicating, exchanging keys, and cleaning.
I do tinker with [the calendar], and I tinker with the price, and I have a different weekend rate, and I change the price for the next two weeks if they’re still empty, so I charge more out front. You know, I’m playing with it, trying to figure it out.
For Taskers, optimization sometimes means a focus on travel distance, time, and costs. Ralph, introduced above, lives about an hour north of Boston and typically gets tasks that require significant driving. He explains his process for deciding whether to take one:
I think about, okay, so how far am I driving? Because my car's really good with gas… when I'm accepting the task, I do a quick calculation. I'm like, okay, so this, this, this… is it worth it? Is it worth it? Yes, it's worth it. Then, boom. I go do it, I get paid. That's it.
Unlike quite a few other maximizers, Ralph does not write the distances down and instead will “go back to it after I get paid to see if I actually benefited,” but his larger orientation is calculative.
Stocksy’s cooperative model includes end-of-year profit-sharing for all members. This leads to maximizers trying to get other members to sell more. Some use the community forums to espouse best practices in hopes that it will encourage others’ maximizing behavior. Stocky’s homines economici are often critical of members who fail to adopt their data-driven strategies. Derrick, a white commercial photographer in his seventies who specializes in industrial photography, says he has found a niche and always strives to become more adept at his specialization to increase his earnings. However, he resents peers that “only wanted beer money” and are not “serious” enough:
They’re not investing, reinvesting into stock, they’re not seeing it as a business. They’re seeing it as an artistic passion and there’s a place for that, God bless them, but that’s not how you build a successful agency. You cannot build it by holding the hands of brand new shooters who don’t know how to run this as a business. They don’t have enough editors, they don’t have enough psychiatrists, they don’t have enough people who can put up with the bullshit.
Almost all earners in this group invest significant time and resources into their platform activities. Taskers buy new tools and build up their skills, Airbnb hosts renovate and decorate their properties, Stocksy members invest money in their equipment and shoots. Juan, a Hispanic 28-year-old who is a full-time accountant and an active Tasker has a keen understanding of the platform, including the diversity of available tasks, skills and education levels required; factors that affect the length of time a task will take (e.g., traffic, the client’s expectations) and the hourly rate. He started a small translation business, securing tasks on TaskRabbit and subcontracting the work to translators he found on Odesk. Investing his own money in these subcontractors allows him to offer a large number of languages. Juan explains that “TaskRabbit is the ultimate capitalist tool, really. I mean, you will make as much money as you’re willing to put the work into.” And while many saw things just in terms of their own efforts, others based their participation on ideas of idealized markets. Mark, who is 32, explains how he deals with the occasional lulls in TaskRabbit demand:
[F]rom the way the markets work, a market term, I know something will come up tomorrow. I don't know how many. I don’t know if I’ll do one job or two jobs… There’s no guarantee… I guess maybe the way any market works. There may be one or two slow days but then everything kind of catches up.
Homo Instrumentalis
As with the other two groups, homines instrumentales are motivated by making money on their respective platforms. This is the primary goal they express during their interviews, similar to homo economici. However, they pursue earnings in a different way. Their activities are frequently centered on a target income, either a pre-set amount, or enough to cover specific expenses, such as rent, or a vacation. To reach their targets, they follow a scattershot approach to pricing and activities, relying on simple heuristics rather than calculations or information-seeking. They are often resistant to expanding their earnings beyond the target or optimizing their pursuit of it. For some, this resistance is rooted in a more tenuous commitment to prioritizing their work on the platform, despite their desire to make money.
Lucy, a white 34-year-old Airbnb host, is a self-described member of the upper class, with assets valued at more than $14 million. She has hosted people on more than 50 occasions, and uses that income to pay for her mortgage and hobby:
I have horses. More than one. They cost a lot of money… Basically I do my Airbnb… to pay the horse board every month… Otherwise it pays the mortgage… money is allocated for those two things.
Elisabeth, a 31-year-old Latina who works full-time on TaskRabbit, is on the other end of the wealth spectrum. She is living at home with her parents, feeling humiliated by the loss of a previous nanny job and the need to ask her parents for money for bus and subway fare. She uses her earnings to see her boyfriend who lives in another state and her goal “is to actually make ten-thousand dollars to go to Israel for a month… That’s a long way off for the time being.”
Earners in this group do not articulate an overarching strategy for how they pursue this income. Instead, they describe patterns of behavior that are the result of simple heuristics that can operate without the commitment of time and resources that go into the decision-making processes of homo economici. Elisabeth explains that she bid for the task of the interview by referring to two focus groups she had done for iPhone apps, for which she’d earned $20 and $40. “So I figured, ‘Okay fine I’ll go somewhere in the middle. I’ll say, you know $25. It’s only an hour.’” She explains that she does cleaning and organization tasks “because they’re quick and easy, honestly. Very straightforward, no hidden things… I want to know that I cleaned your house, it’s clean, and I’m gone. I don’t want things that sort of linger.” Christina, who is white and in her twenties, is a Stocksy member who has successful enterprises as a photographer and yoga instructor outside of the platform. She enjoys balancing different projects, but for her Stocksy is primarily a good way to further monetize work she was already doing, so she snaps a few Stocksy photos during her other gigs. But beyond circulating leftover images, she is not interested in doing Stocksy-specific work.
For some, the simple heuristics are the result of financial struggle. George, a Black visual artist in his late twenties, is dependent on TaskRabbit to pay expenses that aren’t covered by his precarious art-related income. He reports that he would take any task he could get on the platform. “So I was just trying to stay financially stable so that’s why my prices were kind of scattered, like $50 here, $25 here, $100 here.” When we asked him about any risky interactions he might have had with deliveries of packages that may contain illegal items, an issue others have identified (Ravenelle, 2019), he explains:
That’s the thing about me, maybe it’s bad or maybe it’s good but I don’t care. As long as I don’t hear anything ticking in it, I’m all right, I’ll bring it there and that’s it. Like I don’t care, like just because TaskRabbit to me is like out of desperation, like I need this money.
Homines instrumentales are not interested in expanding their work on the platforms or optimizing it to maximize their earnings or minimize their labor. Angela, a 46 year old and white, balances being a “semi-professional photographer” with her university lecturing. She likes that Stocksy allows her to monetize previously neglected work but was wary about investing in photoshoots. To her, the gamble is not worth the risk: “I try not to invest too much into shoots because also I wonder whether or not it will repay.” Theo, an East-Asian 32-year-old Tasker and a recent college graduate who is weighing whether to go to graduate school, turns down anything that requires him to drive or go into the city. Most of his tasks are from the first-come-first-served option on the app. He also dislikes competing with other Taskers, despite his strategy for setting hourly rates:
I generally try to put my rates around average. I do that because I don’t consider myself a professional in these services… I don’t think it would make sense to really charge that much more than other people.
Anna, a 28-year-old South-Asian who hosts on Airbnb on rare occasions, has typical monthly earnings of $150. Describing her price-setting, she shares an interaction she had with a prospective guest: “I think we just said, oh, $100 bucks [a night] sounds right, and we just went for it… they said, well, if we’re staying for two nights, can we just do $150, and we were like, yeah, sure.”
For some people in this category, attachment to the platforms is tenuous. On Stocksy, this lack of commitment translates to a lack of engagement with the cooperative aspects of the platform. Christina, introduced above, puts it best: “I don’t interact with the people too much… I know a lot of fellow photographers are also on the site. So in turn I follow them. I check their stuff out. It’s a very, very small interaction.”
6 Platform Behaviors
An obvious question raised by our findings is whether platforms will continue to tolerate diverse earnings strategies. Given that platform investors and operators generally prioritize growth and subsequently profitability, will they continue to accommodate providers who do not maximize? If they do, it lends credibility to the view that they represent a new kind of hybrid firm. To find out how platforms adapt to provider strategies and to what extent they attempt to modify these behaviors, we draw on our interview data, personal experiences with the platforms, and archived website data from our three cases. Although none of the platforms has eliminated lower-performing earners, all three have made policy changes that nudge providers towards more lucrative earning strategies.
TaskRabbit’s model has evolved in a way that disadvantages homines sociales. Its original setup was a bidding system in which clients posted a task and interested Taskers responded by quoting a rate. Clients then chose among those bids. Taskers had agency in this system and none of the three earner groups were particularly privileged. Moreover, clients and Taskers could discuss prices and details, even outside of the platform. Although highly-reviewed Taskers benefited from the bidding system, less-experienced Taskers could use their profiles and private communications to advocate and establish rapport with clients. In 2014, the company overhauled the system in order to increase the volume of transactions. The new version — an app for smartphones and tablets — lists task categories and blocks off-platform communications. Pricing also went from per task to hourly. Though Taskers set their own hourly wage rates, the platform suggests ranges. Taskers are free to decline requests, but this lowers their acceptance rating and results in lower algorithmic priority. The new system also added a “quick assign” feature in which the algorithm suggests matches. Quick assign simplifies selection but it caters to instrumentales at the expense of sociales, who no longer have access to their established clientele. In addition, the system began to prioritize “Elite Taskers,” a designation which requires completing a significant number of monthly tasks and being in the top five percent of earners on the platform. Given their maximizing tendencies, this created an advantage for economici. Further signs of Tasker professionalization and nudges toward optimizing behavior include new features of the app, such as a dashboard titled “Your Performance,” which highlights “Needs Improvement,” categories such as measures of “Task Acceptance,” “Task Completion,” and “Response Rate.”4
Stocksy has also made efforts to monetize the work of its contributors. Originally, Stocksy recruited well-established photographers to join the platform. More recently, it is expanding its membership to increase and diversify the collection. The staff prioritizes selecting members who mesh well with the existing brand and elevate its aesthetic. In order to minimize competition among members, the staff tries to find “niche” photographers who can add to the collection without cutting into existing members’ profits. While staff attempts to accommodate individual situations, they did hold a vote to institute a cut-off for inactive members. The staff holds weekly editorial meetings and selects pictures to promote in the curated feeds, to highlight more marketable work. Archived data from the website suggests that management has steered the co-op towards more artistic or alternative works, to develop its market niche. In order to protect Stocksy’s brand, staff regularly reject submissions that fail to meet their standards. On the site, photographers have their “Assets” and “Followers” listed — metrics that serve as proxies for the quality or popularity of their work, similar to ratings on TaskRabbit and Airbnb. Photographers are given incentivizes to add large numbers of photos to the archive, but management still tolerates low activity, presumably because low earners do not incur a cost for other co-op members. When photographers experience high rejection rates or low sales, staff reach out to provide guidance and brainstorm solutions. Because Stocksy is a co-op, there are community-wide forums to voice issues, celebrate successes, and discuss the future of the platform. Homines economici reach out to other earners to encourage profit-maximizing and increase shared payouts. When these discussions become heated, staff may step in and “put a pin in them” to de-escalate tensions.
Airbnb has also made changes that are relevant to earner behaviors. In 2015, the platform introduced “smart pricing,” an optional tool that set rates automatically, in order to boost occupancy and earnings. The tool draws on more than 70 different variables to predict “shifts in the market,” such as adjusting for seasonal pricing.5 The platform also introduced “Instant Book,” a feature that lets guests book accommodations without waiting for host approval, not unlike TaskRabbit’s “Quick Assign” feature. Airbnb also started promoting a new insurance policy, thereby reducing guest screening and the need for rapport-building. Reviews have become more detailed, and now include six categories (location, cleanliness, etc.). The online system promises confirmation within 24 hours and measures host response rates to encourage this. Hosts who fail to reply within 24 hours have their response rates reduced, and the pending reservation request is automatically declined. Failure to reply also affects a listing’s search placement. Moreover, the response policy covers replies to messages during a stay, such as requests for information and help. While bookings can still be cancelled, doing so now incurs financial penalties. The company also sanctions hosts who fail to meet review standards. One of our participants — a homo socialis who reduces rates to lower guest expectations — received a warning from Airbnb that cited her ratings of four or less stars. Responsive and highly rated hosts can now earn the title of “Superhost,” which prioritizes their listings. Airbnb is also taking an increasingly interventionist approach as a mediator of exchange: sending frequent email reminders to hosts, prompting responsiveness to bookings, offering tips for increasing earnings, and sanctioning hosts who fail to meet standards. Hosts who wish to be favorably placed in search results now need to read the platform’s fine print and be diligent in their hosting behavior, a modus operandi that suits homines economici.
Notwithstanding the push towards professional standards on Airbnb, there is no meaningful discrimination against low-activity hosts. One can still be a Superhost with infrequent bookings. While designing the smart pricing tool, the company interviewed both hosts who depend on their Airbnb income and supplemental earners, to gauge pricing needs in relation to income goals. Airbnb’s tolerance of differing hosting needs is notable, because it means that homines sociales, the largest group in our Airbnb sample, can continue to choose guests based on personal preferences so long as responsiveness and ratings remain high. On the other hand, the push towards professional hosting standards may be altering guests’ expectations. Many of our participants complained that compared to early adopters, recent guests are less interested in social connection, and the platform’s actions may be exacerbating this trend. We also find that Airbnb’s more stringent demands are less compatible with a homo instrumentalis approach. However, automatic pricing and instant booking features do support this group’s hands-off approach to hosting. Economici in our sample took advantage of some streamlining features like instant booking, but continued to make individual calculations.
Surveying platform actions over the first decade, we find that platform earners are managed from afar, sometimes with a firm hand, but more often in subtle ways that sustain autonomy. For instance, Airbnb tells hosts how to increase their margins by using its pricing and booking tools, rather than helping them use the platform’s affordances for sociability. These efforts arguably nudge participants towards adopting a double-entry-bookkeeping perspective on hosting, but do not mandate it. Opportunities for maximizing are further enhanced by a growing list of auxiliary services associated with platforms. These include Taskers subcontracting out work, Airbnb hosts hiring professional cleaners, or Stocksy artists employing assistants. The sociales and instrumentales in our sample might resist pushes towards maximizing behavior especially on Stocksy and Airbnb, where occasional participation is still acceptable. For economici, there may be a growing tension between agency and efficiency as more processes become automatic.
Larger, external factors are also affecting platform changes, such as regulatory policies and competition from other companies. On-demand services have seen increased pressure from labor activists and politicians to classify workers as employees, in order to grant them essential rights that independent contractors lack, such as a minimum wage and unemployment benefits. This is not an immediate threat to any of our platforms, but competitive pressures and market conditions are relevant to all three. TaskRabbit faces strong competition from other on-demand labor sites, and has moved away from deliveries, at least in part due to the emergence of major courier and food delivery apps. Though Stocksy’s “boutique” aesthetic initially set the co-op apart from Getty and Alamy, those industry giants have begun to imitate the Stocksy brand. In an attempt to counter these moves and gain economies of scale, Stocksy partnered with Adobe Stock in 2017 and increased membership in order to meet the demands of an expanding clientele. However, this has resulted in unintended competition among Stocksy photographers as more members enter existing niches. Airbnb, by far the largest of our three platforms, grew in part because it resided for years in a gray area between work, subletting, and “sharing.” This ambiguous classification helped market actors escape taxes on their income, making it more profitable and attractive, which in turn boosted the company’s capacity for expansion. Moreover, the company’s dominant position in the home-sharing market gave it ample time to experiment with how to operate a platform with a plurality of participant motivations. Increased regulatory pressure might change this. In 2019, Airbnb commenced automatic collection of State Sales Taxes and Local Occupancy Taxes in Massachusetts, where our participants reside, and similar initiatives have been implemented elsewhere. The platform’s success has also encouraged a number of resourceful challengers, including Marriott International.
7 Conclusion
How can we theorize these digital platforms? We have argued for seeing them as hybrid entities that give earners more control over their actions than conventional firms, but which also exercise distinct mechanisms of control. We found that multiple approaches to earning co-exist within a platform: homo economicus, homo socialis, and homo instrumentalis. We then asked, is the continued presence of the latter two groups, who typically work and earn less, sustainable for the companies? To answer that question, we reviewed relevant policies and platform affordances. We found that all three companies have instituted changes that nudge providers in the direction of a maximizing orientation, with TaskRabbit being the most aggressive in this regard. However, their behaviors are nudges, rather than directives. None of the three have made it impossible for lower-activity participants, or homines sociales and instrumentales to continue on the platforms. The platforms appear to be tolerating the diversity we have identified. This suggests that the hybrid designation, as theorized by Watkins and Stark, Kornberger et al, and Vallas and Schor, is robust to the presence of multiple earning orientations.
That said, there is some movement in the direction of promoting the modus operandi of homo economicus, via platform design, management practices, and the broader ecosystem of auxiliary services. Many of the market devices that modify behavior in our three cases — response rates, popularity metrics, elite status and curated ordering of entities for sale — are standard in the gig sector. A central question for further research is how will earners respond to these converging trends? In particular, what happens to those who feel that the platform economy no longer works for their original goals? Do they assimilate; do they seek out alternative platforms; or do they give up on platform work altogether? And as these and related platforms grow into their second decade, will regulatory and market forces make it difficult for them to host the heterogeneous earners that we have found in the first decade?
References
Aneesh, A. (2009). Global Labor: Algocratic Modes of Organization. Sociological Theory, 27(4), 347–370. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01352.x
Beckert, J. (1996). What Is Sociological about Economic Sociology? Uncertainty and the Embeddedness of Economic Action. Theory and Society, 25(6), 803–840. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00159817
Beckert, J. (2003). Economic Sociology and Embeddedness: How Shall We Conceptualize Economic Action? Journal of Economic Issues, 37(3), 769–787. https://doi.org/10.1080/00213624.2003.11506613
Block, F.L., & Somers, M.R. (2014). The Power of Market Fundamentalism: Karl Polanyi’s Critique. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Bourdieu, P. (1984). Distinction: A Social Critique of the Judgement of Taste. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Camerer, C, Babcock, L., Lowenstein, G., & Thaler, R. (1997). Labor Supply of New York City Cab Drivers: One Day At A Time. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 407–441. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555244
Cameron, L.D. (2018). Making out While Driving: Control, Coordination, and Its Consequences in Algorithmic Work. Wharton Ideas Lab. https://ideas.wharton.upenn.edu/research/boss-algorithm/
Caplin, A., Dean, M., & Martin D. (2011). Search and Satisficing. American Economic Review, 101(7), 2899–2922. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.101.7.2899
Chen, L., Mislove, A., & Wilson, C. (2015). Peeking Beneath the Hood of Uber. Proceedings of the 2015 ACM Conference on Internet Measurement Conference – IMC ’15 (pp. 495–508). Tokyo, Japan: ACM Press.
Cullen, Z., & Farronato, C. (2018). Outsourcing Tasks Online: Matching Supply and Demand on Peer-to-Peer Internet Platforms. Management Science. Informs. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2020.3730
Davis, G.F. (2016a). The Vanishing American Corporation: Navigating the Hazards of a New Economy. San Francisco, CA: Berrett-Kohler.
Davis, G.F. (2016b). What Might Replace the Modern Corporation?: Uberization and the Web Page Enterprise. Seattle University Law Review, 39, 501–515. http://webuser.bus.umich.edu/gfdavis/Papers/Davis_SULR_2016.pdf
Dobbin, F.A. (2007). Economic Sociology. In C.D. Bryant & D.L. Peck (Eds.), Twenty-First Century Sociology: A Reference Handbook (pp. 319–331). Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE.
van Doorn, N., & Badger, A. (2020). Platform Capitalism’s Hidden Abode: Producing Data Assets in the Gig Economy. Platform Capitalism’s Hidden Abode. Antipode, 52(5), 1475–1495. https://doi.org/10.1111/anti.12641
Dubal, V. (2017). Wage-Slave or Entrepreneur? Contesting the Dualism of Legal Worker Categories. California Law Review, 105, 65–126. https://doi.org/10.15779/Z38M84X
Einav, L., Farronato, C., & Levin, J. (2016). Peer-to-Peer Markets. Annual Review of Economics, 8(1), 615–635. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-080315-015334
Fitzmaurice, C.J., Ladegaard, I., Attwood-Charles, W., Cansoy, M., Carfagna, L.B., Schor, J.B., & Wengronowitz, R. (2020). Domesticating the Market: Moral Exchange and the Sharing Economy. Socio-Economic Review, 18(1), 81–102. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwy003
Folbre, N. (2001). The Invisible Heart: Economics and Family Values. New York, NY: New Press.
Fridman, D. (2020). This Is a Handicraft: Valuation, Morality and the Social Meanings of Payments for Psychoanalysis.
Grabher, G., & van Tuijl, E. (2020). Uber-Production: From Global Networks to Digital Platforms. Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space, 52(5), 1005–1016. https://doi.org/10.1177/0308518X20916507
Granovetter, M.S. (1973). The Strength of Weak Ties. American Journal of Sociology, 78(6), 1360–1380. https://doi.org/10.1086/225469
Griesbach, K., Reich, A., Elliott-Negri, L., & Milkman, R. (2019). Algorithmic Control in Platform Food Delivery Work. Socius: Sociological Research for a Dynamic World, 5, 1–15. https://doi.org/10.1177/2378023119870041
Horton, J.J., & Zeckhauser, R.J. (2016). Owning, Using and Renting: Some Simple Economics of the “Sharing Economy”. NBER Working Paper, 22029. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2730850
Jensen, M.C., & Meckling, W.H. (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X
Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux.
Kalleberg, A.L. (2013). Good Jobs, Bad Jobs: The Rise of Polarized and Precarious Employment Systems in the United States, 1970s to 2000s. New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.
Kenney, M., & Zysman, J. (2019). Work and Value Creation in the Platform Economy. In S.P. Vallas & A. Kovalainen (Eds.), Work and Labor in the Digital Age (pp. 13–41). Vol. 33, Research in the Sociology of Work. Binkley, UK: Emerald Group Publishing Limited.
Kornberger, M., Pflueger, D., & Mouritsen, J. (2017). Evaluative Infrastructures: Accounting for Platform Organization. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 60, 79–95. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.aos.2017.05.002
Ladegaard, I., Ravenelle, A., & Schor, J.B. (2018). Provider Vulnerability in the Sharing Economy. Unpublished paper, Boston College.
Leidner, Robin. 1993. Fast Food, Fast Talk. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Manriquez, M. (2019). The Uberization of the Labor Market: A Case Study of Monterrey, Mexico. Research in the Sociology of Work. https://www.ilpc.org.uk/Portals/7/2018/Documents/PaperUpload/ILPC2018paper-MarianaManriquez_ILPC2018_20180228_050520.pdf
PEW Research Center. (2016a). Gig Work, Online Selling and Home Sharing. Pew Research Center: Numbers, Facts and Trends Shaping the World. https://www.pewresearch.org/internet/wp-content/uploads/sites/9/2016/11/PI_2016.11.17_Gig-Workers_FINAL.pdf
PEW Research Center. (2016b). Shared, Collaborative and On Demand: The New Digital Economy. Pew Research Center: Internet, Science & Tech. http://www.pewinternet.org/2016/05/19/the-new-digital-economy/
Ravenelle, A.J. (2017). Sharing Economy Workers: Selling, Not Sharing. Cambridge Journal Of Regions, Economy And Society, 10(2), 281–295. https://doi.org/10.1093/cjres/rsw043
Ravenelle, A.J. (2019). Hustle and Gig: Struggling and Surviving in the Sharing Economy. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Robinson, H.C. (2017). Making a Digital Working Class: Uber Drivers in Boston, 2016–2017. Thesis: Ph.D. in History, Anthropology, and Science, Technology and Society (HASTS), Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Program in Science, Technology and Society, 2017. http://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/113946
Rosenblat, A., & Stark, L. (2016). Algorithmic Labor and Information Asymmetries: A Case Study of Uber’s Drivers. International Journal of Communication, 10, 3758–3784. https://ijoc.org/index.php/ijoc/article/view/4892/1739
Schor, J.B., & Vallas, S. (2021). The Sharing Economy: Rhetoric and Reality. Annual Review of Sociology, 47. Forthcoming.
Schor, J.B., Attwood-Charles,W., Cansoy, M., Carfagna, L.B., Eddy, S., Fitzmaurice, C.J., Ladegaard, I., & Wengronowitz, R. (2020a). After the Gig: How the Sharing Economy Got Hijacked and How to Win It Back. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Schor, J.B., Attwood-Charles, W., Cansoy, M., Ladegaard, I., & Wengronowitz, R. (2020b). Dependence and Precarity in the Platform Economy. Theory and Society, 49, 833–861. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-020-09408-y
Schor, J.B., & Cansoy, M. (2019). The Sharing Economy. In F.F. Wherry & I. Woodward (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Consumption (pp. 51–74). New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Simon, H.A. (1957). Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision Making Processes in Administratiive Organization. New York: MacMillan.
Srnicek, N. (2016). Platform Capitalism. Cambridge, UK: Polity.
Sundararajan, A. (2016). The Sharing Economy: The End of Employment and the Rise of Crowd-Based Capitalism. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Vallas, S.P., & Schor, J.B. (2020). What Do Platforms Do? Understanding the Gig Economy. Annual Review of Sociology, 46, 273–294. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-soc-121919-054857
Watkins, E.A., & Stark, D. (2018). The Möbius Organizational Form: Make, Buy, Cooperate, or Co-Opt? Sociologica, 12(1), 65–80. https://doi.org/10.6092/issn.1971-8853/8364
Weil, D. (2014). The Fissured Workplace: Why Work Became So Bad for So Many and What Can Be Done to Improve It. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Zelizer, V.A. (2012). How I Became a Relational Economic Sociologist and What Does That Mean? Politics & Society, 40(2), 145–174. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F0032329212441591
Zelizer, V.A. (2013). Economic Lives: How Culture Shapes the Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Another “permissive” aspect of platform work is that earners are permitted to work for competitor firms. One reason is to provide on-demand labor supply. Another may be to conform better with regulations governing employment classification (Independent Contractor versus Employee Status) (Dubal, 2017). However, while this concern may be governing the actions of a few smaller platforms, it seems not to be an overriding issue for some large ones, such as Uber, Lyft, and some delivery platforms.↩︎
While ideas such as target incomes were common among economists in the past, they have become less so recently. An influential paper on income targeting among NYC taxi drivers (Camerer et al., 1997) has been challenged by an Uber study which found that although some drivers start with target income strategies, many transitioned to maximizing behaviors (Chen et al., 2015).↩︎
A few Airbnb earners were excluded from our sample because they had not operated on the platform long enough to establish an identifiable behavioral orientation.↩︎
http://www.designbychrislam.com/taskrabbit-tasker-experience↩︎
https://airbnb.design/smart-pricing-how-we-used-host-feedback-to-build-personalized-tools/↩︎